Friday, July 31, 2009

WORLD SYSTEM EVOLUTION


George Modelski

Department of Political Science

University of Washington

Prepared for the conference on

WORLD SYSTEM HISTORY: THE SOCIAL SCIENCE OF LONG-TERM CHANGE

University of Lund, Sweden, March 25-29, 1995

(revised)

WORLD SYSTEM EVOLUTION

If the question is: what explains the development of the world system over the past 5000 years of its history, then our answer is: world system development is the product of an evolutionary process, or better still, of an array of evolutionary processes.

We therefore propose here that world system history be examined in the first place as an incident in the evolution of the human species; world system is one form that the organization of humanity can assume, and clarifying it is one way the boundaries of the concept can be ascertained. Secondly, we propose that the structural components of world system, such as economic, political, social, or cultural, are each subject to evolutionary processes, each of a distinct character but each subject to the same basic set of mechanisms. We assume finally that all of these evolutionary processes are not randomly scattered but rather exhibit synchronization of a co-evolutionary character.

Such a conception yields a number of conjectures about the shape and timing of world development. It is a conception that is especially fruitful for viewing the big picture of the behavior of the human species in the large; it yields a periodization of world history as a phased evolution of the world system; it serves as a way of ordering the growth of the world economy, and of world politics, and the accretion of a world community; and for the last millennium of our experience it affords a finer-grained depiction of structural change at the global level, with especial attention to the rise of world powers. Miraculously, all these separate processes seem to be interdependent and well synchronized.

All of this is a theoretical conjecture that amounts to the spinning out of a few basic rules of evolutionary processes. But unlike 19th century schemes of evolutionism, it also purports to be capable of being tested. Correspondences between these conjectures and standard accounts of world history will be noted, and certain other supporting evidence will also be discussed. But the principal purpose of this paper is to lay out the basic logic of this argument, and the way in which all of it forms an interrelated, symmetric, and mutually supporting structure that in turn gains in strength from being grounded in evolutionary theory.

World system evolution is the story of humans learning to live with each other, and learning to do so in global proportions. It is the story not of a movement guided either purely by instinct or in accordance with a prearranged plan or toward a given end, but rather that of a continual and continuing search pursued in accordance with the laws of evolutionary process.

RISE OF THE WORLD SYSTEM

A process definition

Let us begin by establishing a definition of our basic term, world system, and make that a "process" definition. We define the rise of the world system as "the process of advancing the social and conceptual organization of the human species, actual or potential". In other words, our interest lies not in mapping the state of the world system at a point in time, but in gaining a conceptual purchase upon large -scale temporal social change. Let us look at the implications of the several parts of that definition in greater detail.

On this view, world system is, in the first place, a form of species organization. A species is a population of individuals that interbreed and that share common attributes and a common fate; forming a complex system, it is a collection of organisms that is subject to evolutionary processes. Biologists inform us that the number of living species of animals on this planet is of the order of one million (Lumsden and Wilson 1981:4) and about each of these the question might be asked: how is that species organized, and how well is it organized? For by the condition of interbreeding alone, members of a species are intimately related, and share important symbioses that include forms of social organization. They signal in order to establish mutual recognition as members of the same species, they cooperate if only in the processes of reproduction; they experience competition and conflict, and they depend on certain resources in order to survive, and continue breeding.

But Lumsden and Wilson (ibid.,3-7) also argue that the human species is unique in the magnitude of its enculturation process. "Mankind has attained" the "complete" or "true" cultural state because its repertoire includes not only simple learning and imitation, but also complex learning: teaching linked to socialization of the young, and the employment of symbols by human agents. This creates the potential for more advanced forms of social organization.

World system is the product of these processes but it is, above all, a form of social organization, a structure (that is, a relatively long-lasting pattern) of social relationships. As social action we consider it for analytical purposes to be distinct from, though interrelated with, types of action systems that are psychological, cultural, or behavioral. The chief question we ask of this structure is not: does it exist, because we postulate that, in varying degrees, it does as an emerging and ongoing process; but how it changes. World system changes, or transformations, may then be seen as major shifts in the social patterns of the human species. But the focus of this analysis of world system is organization, and not culture as complex meanings and the codes that govern it, nor changes in the make-up of personalities, or the adaptations in the behavioral organism that mediate between the physical organism and human action.

As social organization , world system changes may, of course, be decomposed, on the vertical dimension, into global, regional, national, and local layers, and on the horizontal dimension, into their economic, political, societal, cultural (strictly-speaking, culture-reproductive) structures. In this sense, we might envisage a fully developed world system to comprise world economy, world political system, world community, and world cultural system, each of which might also exhibit global, regional, etc. elements. These components are not randomly assembled; each occupies a distinct position in the world social structure.

We do not subscribe to an economic-determinist position that would view the economy, as division of labor, as the basic unit, but we might rank the economy as, in the shorter run, the most basic of these structures, followed by politics, society, and culture; but we might also argue that those institutions that shape and transmit widely held values, are the most important for long-range social organization, followed by societal, political, and last of all, economic arrangements.

The empirical referent of world system are the networks of interactions linking the members of the human species. Such networks form the basis of the world system when they are potentially, or actually, planetary, or world-wide in scope. Should humans come to settle other planets, but remain in contact with the Earth, then the pattern of their activities, and their relationships would also be comprised under the term of world system. But species-wide interactions are the property of the human species and antedate the world system. We do not, at one point, see a world system because we can point to the evidence of interactions; only if these interactions evince certain characteristics and a certain structure. That is, our primary task is not the mapping of interaction networks, and asking if they are world-wide, but rather the explanation of a learning process.

In its distribution, the human species has been world-wide, that is reaching every continent, for some time now, homo sapiens sapiens (anatomically modern humans) having expanded, probably on the basis of superior skills in communication by language, from Africa to every continent by, at the latest, 15,000 years ago (Asia, 60,000 , Europe, 35,000, Australia, 40,000, the Americas 35,000-15,000; Cavalli-Sforza et al. 1994:112,154-7). But its organization was obviously lacking and did not satisfy the minimum conditions of world system: common identity, solidarity, sources of collective action, and a resource base, that would establish at least a potential for species-wide undertakings. That is why one question for this analysis is to establish the transition from "less advanced" to "advanced", that is from pre-world system to world system, forms of species organization whose formation is still underway.

A 'singular' world system

All this discussion presupposes what we might call the 'singular' conception of world system. Such a conception maintains that the human species has, throughout its existence exhibited, and will continue to exhibit, important regularities and common behavioral patterns, not only at the level of individuals but also at the collective level of common rules and institutions. It stands for the idea that the behavioral uniformities of humanity viewed as an interacting whole are worth knowing about, and the changes in those characteristics, a most important object of study for the social sciences.

There are some interesting parallels here with interdisciplinary debates about the origins of modern humans. On the plural (or polycentric) view, homo sapiens sapiens emerged, in the past several hundred thousand years, separately but by parallel evolution to form distinct races in the world's major regions. The "singular" view, that is supported by contemporary genetic research, as reported by Cavalli-Sforza (1994:p.62 ff), sees to-day's world population as the product of a single expansion of "antomically modern humans" from Africa over the past one hundred thousand years.

The singular conception of world system (as shown e.g. in Frank and Gills 1993) might be contrasted with the 'plural' one, that which proceeds from the existence of a plurality of world systems (as e.g. in Chase-Dunn and Hall, 1991, Wilkinson 1991). These are called 'world' systems mostly not because they extended actually or potentially to the whole of the human species or because they covered the entire planet but because they are deemed to have been self-contained or regarded by their members as 'worlds-in-themselves'. In the plural conception a major question becomes that of system identity, of relations among world systems, and the merger of world systems into "super"-world systems: where do we draw the boundaries, and how do world systems merge into the contemporary, "singular" one.

Our own preference would be to use terms such as "regional" or "local" for systems that may seem to have been self-sufficient, or whose distinctive characteristics appear to confer a special identity, and reserve the term world system to that one whose operations, potentially or actually, are coextensive with humanity. The distinction is not unimportant. It is not merely an idiosyncratic choice between "lumpers" and "splitters": between those who see things writ large, and others who see reality, in the first place, only in the microcosm. It is also a choice between the sort of question one deems important: a broad-gauged inquiry into the behavior of humanity, or a detailed accounting of the fates of individual societies each interesting in their own right, that might also, in the aggregate, add up to the story of humanity. This difference is not a new one, and it revives debates that have been current for some time in the study of world history.

For Condorcet, in his pioneering account of human progress, or for Immanuel Kant, in his concept of "universal history", the story of the world was, in the first place, the story of humanity. For those thinkers there was only one (evolving) world system, and one world civilization. Contrast this with influential conceptions of "multiple" (or plural) civilizations viewed, in Arnold Toynbee's (1934:51) words as "the intelligible field" of history conceived as the "comparative study of civilizations". For Toynbee, as for Oswald Spengler, "civilizations" were the societies that had a "greater extension, both in Space and in Time than national states or city states" but none of which embraced "the whole of Mankind" (ib.,p.45). The story of mankind was for them an account of the life cycles of these distinct civilizations, of which he identified more than twenty.

This "plural" perspective, of a number of separate civilizations pursuing essentially independent careers may be contrasted with McNeill's (1963,1991) position that the cultures of mankind have experienced a significant degree of interactions with other cultures at every stage of their history and never more so when great transformations were underway in the world system. For McNeill, the present state of world organization is the consummation of a single continuous process that he recently (1991:xxii) described as "ecumenical".

We find the "unitary" conception potentially more economical than the plural, even though the two are not at all mutually exclusive. Given our interests, we find less useful the Toynbeean concept of a plurality of civilizations and adopt instead a 'singular" or 'unitary' view of the human project as a quest for pushing to its full the potential for species organization. The story of world system development then becomes that of the search for actualization world system potential via learning.

WORLD SYSTEM EVOLUTION

The explicandum: structural change

A process definition of the world system naturally focuses attention upon sequences of change in the social organization of humanity. But which, more specifically, are those changes that need to be explained?

We propose the following four sets of changes in the world system are the proper targets of explanation:

1. Epochs of world system history, -3500 - +2000; the conventional periodization of the story of the human community; what explains those major watersheds of human development?

2. World system development: how the economic, political, social and cultural structures of the world system have risen, both separately and in tandem with one another;

3. The modern global system and its inception, and in particular the world powers as drivers of economic and political growth;

4. The onset of civilization: ca.-3500, hence also the inception of the world system; what constitutes civilization?

These are, at different levels of analysis, four sets of questions about key aspects of the growth of the world system in the past five thousand years. The first looks upon the world system as a whole. The second distinguishes between the several horizontal structures of the world system, and the third focuses upon a prominent vertical structure of the modern world, the global system. The last concerns human evolution as such. All four pose large questions and they demand solid explanations.

The explanans: evolutionary logic

To answer these large questions about the social organization of the human race we employ an evolutionary explanation. What constitutes an evolutionary explanation in this case? (See also Modelski 1994; Andersen 1994:14).

A social-evolutionary explanation is an explanation of a fact of social life by reference to previous facts as well as to a causal link that may be shown to include:

(1) a mechanism of variety-creation;

(2) a mechanism of cooperation (and segregation);

(3) a mechanism of selection, and

(4) a mechanism of preservation and transmission.

World system processes, at their several levels of analysis, are each an integration of these four mechanisms. As a very rough approximation we might say that the first of these mechanisms is cultural, the second social, the third, political, and the fourth, economic. Since such a synthesis has to be an ordered one, all world system processes have a time-structure that allows for successive optimizations of these mechanisms in a sequence that is a learning sequence (or algorithm), represented in the order in which these mechanisms were presented in the preceding paragraph. World system processes therefore possess the make-up of a four-phase temporal learning experience.

The crucial underlying hypothesis here is that of constant rate of evolutionary change. That is the hypothesis of a "molecular clock" timing genetic mutations over long time periods, and helping to explain the time elapsed in the separation of two species. Cavalli-Sforza and associates (1994:33) use that same postulate to study the history and geography of human genes. They define the rate of evolution as the amount of evolutionary change - measured as the genetic distance between an ancestor and a descendant - divided by the time in which it occurred, and they report to have found that the hypothesis yields good results when used to compare major population changes. A directly analogous procedure has also been employed in linguistic analysis and is known as glottochronology (Swadesh 1971:271) and is used to date the origin of languages by assuming a constant rate of replacement: a "relatively constant rhythm of substitution" in a basic vocabulary, with an average retention rate of some 86 per cent per one thousand years. Results from linguistic work tend to reinforce genetic studies even though the rate of genetic change is, of course, much slower than that of languages.

This leads to the following postulates:

1. World system processes, at all levels, are evolutionary in character; they are self-similar in that the same explanatory logic applies at each level, implying that the system has a fractal structure. Self-similarity is "symmetry across scale", a "repetition of structure at finer and finer scales" (Gleick 1987:103,100).

2. World system processes undergo change at a constant rate, and have a phased time-structure that integrates the four evolutionary mechanisms of variety-creation, cooperation, selection, and reinforcement. Each period of an evolutionary process consists of the four phases of the learning process.

3. World system processes flourish in conditions conducive to innovation.

4. All world system processes are nested and synchronized (they co-evolve). Nesting means that large-scale processes enfold, and are in turn animated by, smaller scale processes of determinate proportion in conditions of synchronization.

In other words we do not search for a distinct logic for each era or structure of the world system; "one system" rewquires "one process". We propose one common logic (or algorithm), an evolutionary one, for the explanation of every world system process.

Sources for evolutionary explanation

The classical source of l9th century philosophies of history is Immanuel Kant's "Idea for a Universal History" (1784, 1991). Kant himself was not an evolutionist, but his basic ideas might be thought of as foundational for evolutionary explanations. He raised the question whether it is possible to discover, among free-willed human actions considered on a large scale, "a regular progression", "in accordance with natural laws", in the "history of the entire species", such that it might be recognized as a "steadily advancing but slow development of man's original capacities". He also put forward nine propositions as guidelines for such a history, the fourth of which identifies "antagonisms in society" as the long-run source of a "law-governed social order" and comes close to portraying them as mechanisms of selection. We cannot but take heart in the ninth proposition, that "a philosophical attempt to work out a universal history of the world in accordance with a plan of nature ... must be regarded as possible" and read it as a prescription of a search for a better theory of the world system, though we need to debate in what sense and to what degree such a "plan of nature" might be thought to be "aimed at a perfect civil union of mankind".

Nineteenth century evolutionary thought assumed two main forms. The founders of sociology, Auguste Comte and Herbert Spencer, advanced bold evolutionary conceptions of the development of humanity, but while aspects of their conceptualizations, of a phased advance toward industrial society, remain influential to this day, they are on the whole regarded as dated. Marxist thought developed along similar lines. This broad "evolutionist" strand of thought might be contrasted with the "selectionist" approach of Charles Darwin, whose revolutionary contribution was the identification of natural selection, and variation, as mechanisms of species development. Darwin also launched the idea of a "tree of life", the common origin of life on earth, and in effect also launched a macro-history of biology; but he avoided any grand claims to explaining patterns of human social evolution.

Social evolutionary thought experienced a revival in mid-20th century, just as Darwinian biology was reinvigorated through the "modern synthesis". In economics, the work of Joseph Schumpeter, among others, is now recognized as "evolutionary", and viewed as an important alternative to neo-classical analysis. In sociology, Talcott Parsons was, in his later work, a significant contributor to social evolutionary theory. More recent social thought has been less hospitable to such theorizing. Anthony Giddens (1984:243,236-9), for example, compounding evolutionary theory with historical materialism, has argued that it is necessary to deconstruct them both. "In explaining social change, no single and sovereign mechanism can be specified. There are no keys that will unlock the mysteries of human social development ..." "Human history does not have an evolutionary shape"; history is not a 'world-growth story' because the relatively short period since the emergence of civilization in Mesopotamia "is not marked by the continuing ascent of civilization; it conforms more to Toynbee's picture of the rise and fall of civilizations".

We disagree with this position, and attempt a synthesis of "evolutionism" with "selectionism". That is, we aim to explain large-scale social change, but seek to do it by carefully tracing the processes and the mechanisms that propel such change, and " selection" is the chief one, though not the only of these mechanisms, as just noted.

In social theory, we need to contrast the evolutionary explanation with rational choice, and with functionalism. Rational choice (Elster 1989), whose paradigm is neo-classical economic analysis, is an elaboration of what Max Weber called the ends-means schema. That schema takes opportunities (and constraints), as well as preferences (or interests), as given and generates from them a stream of intended outcomes. By contrast, selectionist and evolutionary models do not depend upon intentions; they focus on actual outcomes, and they make changes in constraints and interests as part of the model. Design, the ideal product of rational choice, is not part of selection that plays upon trial-and- error. Speed of response is the glory of rational choice; evolutionary change is the tortoise that moves slowly but surely over the long haul.

Selectionist models therefore seem preferable for studying evolutionary processes and macro-level phenomena such as world system change. Nor are they to be confused with functionalism. Classical functionalism asked: what maintains social structures? The answer was, a practice that responds to a (postulated) social need. Critics (such as Little 1991;101-20) are right in arguing that this implies an excessively optimistic, "Panglossian" meta-theory, that "societies will produce practices that satisfy their long-term needs". Evolutionary explanations, on the other hand, seek to explain not persistence but social change and the processes that transform social structures.

ERAS OF EMERGING WORLD SYSTEM

A periodization of world history

Schemas of historical periodization are accepted ways of identifying, and describing, long-range social change. William McNeill's (1963) periodization of world history (and shown in first column of Table 1) might be regarded as a standard specification of changes in the world system in the past 5000 years or so (but see also comments in 1991:xvii-xix). That periodization is based on the factor of "dominance", and relies therefore, in the first place, on changes in large-scale political organization. Hence it might illuminate only one facet of the world system process, but there is no reason to suppose that it is unimportant or that it is not intimately related to the other principal components of the world system. Indeed, there are grounds for thinking of political periodicity as a kind of "clock", timing the entire social system. In any event, these periods conform quite comfortably with the headings under which these matters are conventionally arranged: those of ancient, classical, and modern history.

CLICK HERE FOR TABLE 1

On McNeill's account, the political organization of the world system has now passed through three stages. In the first, starting well before -3000, the Middle East was the center of world development. In the second, no one region of the world occupied a similarly striking position, and the situation was, on the contrary one of "cultural balance" in which "each of the four major civilizations developed more or less freely along its own lines" (1963:253). The third stage might be thought of as a return to dominance, and this time, "Western dominance". The long term vision of the future, hence also possibly of a fourth phase, is indicated, by a reference in the book's closing pages, to the "establishment of a world-wide cosmopolitanism" (a Kantian term) that "would enjoy vastly greater stability" (ibid.:806-7).

Shifts in the patterns of dominance might suggest no more than world-wide reshufflings of power structures, but they also serve as useful markers of world time. If we combine our phases with demographic data in Table 2, we observe over the entire period a tremendous growth in the world population since before the (postulated) inception of the world system. To each of the conventional stages, with population measured roughly at mid-point, corresponds a new order of demographic magnitude. Throughout "history", that expanding population shows a fairly even distribution in space, with the major regions of Asia invariably accounting for more than one half of the world total. What we have here is a vast expansion in the membership of the human species as a whole, hence a systemic process, one that must have been associated with significant structural changes, in all dimensions of social organization, one of which was urbanization.

CLICK HERE FOR TABLE 2

Explaining the phase movement

What we have here is a process with a strong phase-structure, both political and social (demographic), that also is suggestively cumulative and in a sense progressive. How do we explain the phasing of this process?

We propose an evolutionary explanation. We argue that the process is one of the emergence of the world system. Or else we say that the process is one of launching of the world system as a major social innovation. The standard periodization reflects the political phasing of that process, and the cumulative demography reflects successively more effective conditions of world organization. Each phase of that process, broadly corresponding to the eras of the conventional periodization, is marked also by the optimization of one of the four major evolutionary mechanisms.

Our model therefore proposes that the evolution of the world system passes through four phases: those of culture-base (laying the basis for variety-generation), community-building (building the foundations for large-scale cooperation); collective organization (selection of forms of world organization), and consolidation (reinforcement and replication). These would represent successive optimizations of evolutionary mechanisms in relation to the world system process. They might also be seen as phases of the learning process that Talcott Parsons and his associates described in 1950 as the LIGA sequence (Modelski 1987:104ff), a sequence that constitutes a learning program. If structural change, that is social learning viewed as problem-solving, is to occur, these phases must be passed in the sequence just presented, in that the completion of one phase depends of conditions created by the preceding phase, and becomes a necessary condition for the phase that follows. Each of the phases represents the principal theme of the world social universe in major epochs of its functioning; they reflect major social priorities but need not imply total neglect of other domains of social organization.

The first phase (in Table 1), labeled "culture-base" might be understood as generating the variety for building the world system, and does so by drawing upon the resources developed in the preceding era (in this case, the agricultural revolution). That variety arises in the context of city-building and gradually spreads, in a system of interconnecting networks in intercontinental proportions: cities being by definition cultural constructions that are oriented to, and closely linked with, other cities, coming to form the base of the world system. The essential feature, and the key innovation of the culture base becomes writing. Writing organizes social life both to the past and to the future; it lends it continuity and makes systematic structural changes possible. It leads to the growth of schools, hence education, and professional classes (e.g. scribes, and teachers); it is centered on temples, and helps, as do cit ies, in differentiating culture from the social system. Writing means the start of systematic learning, and of science (as in astronomy, calendars), makes irrigation possible, and is essential in disseminating the elements of bureaucracy and organization.

Proceeding from the culture-base thus formulated, the next major phase of world system formation goes on to community- building on a scale extending beyond tribe and city. This phase innovates the structures of wider cooperation implicit in the world system, because potentially such cooperation must extend to all humanity. We propose that in this, second phase of the world system process such potential assumes the form of universa l religions. Religion, in turn, forms the basis for solidarity and cooperation, enhances communication and education, large-scale political organization, and long-distance trade. Each in their own way, the great religions are in turn forms of differentiating populations and building large regional ensembles.

Given a set of major communities, the stage is ready for organizational selection. Competitive pressure in the world system selects the organizational forms best attuned to the emerging complexities of the world system. The collective management of human affairs becomes an operative problem, both at national and global levels. Such collective organization finally paves the way for adaptation, a stabilization comprising an adaptive adjustment to the environment, yet preparing the stage for yet other evolutionary developments.

Testing the model

How does our model square with the conventional periodization of the history of humanity? To do this, let us compare the columns in Table 1, where the two to the left show the major divisions of world history and that on the right suggests ways of conceptualizing them. In both instances the dating starts at about -3500, a round figure for the start of the Sumerian era, but we do need to observe some differences between the two presentations. The left column consists of periods of unequal length that nevertheless average out to a little over 2000 years; the right-hand column world system phases are postulated to be of roughly uniform length, just over 2000 years. Unless shown to be otherwise, the assumption of constant rate of change and phase uniformity holds greater initial plausibility because of requirements of synchronization. The (four-phased) world system process would then extend over 8000 years.

Can the era of "Middle Eastern dominance" be correctly described as a phase of "culture-base", as predicted by the model? We observe, first of all, that the Middle East was not dominant in the sense that it might have "controlled" say, China, or Europe, but because it was the location of the major innovations of that period. That is where the first systems of writing appeared, thus effecting the transition from oral to written culture, a major breakthrough in social organization, setting in motion the differentiation of the cultural system from society. This was also the area where cities first emerged, and cities were the first great human artifacts that manifested human cultural achievement, but also laid the foundation for an entirely new form of social organization, becoming the core of civilization. Both stimulated new departures in society, speeded up technological innovation, as in astronomy, civil engineering, and irrigation, laying down the groundwork of conditions in the absence of which a world system could not be constructed and on the basis of which the great religions rose in the next era. The end of the period, "a major turning point in the history of civilization" (McNeill 1963:249) brought "the democratization of learning implicit in simplified scripts", making possible the spread of literacy, hence access to information, among wider and wider segments of society. It also saw the spread of cities to other regions of the world.

To reinforce what might be an unfamiliar argument about the emergence of a "culture-base" of the world system, we present, in Table 3, for the entire span of the world system to-date, a summary of the evolution of external means of transmitting information. Such technologies are the essential preconditions to the creation of variety, hence a sine qua non of evolution, and the table reveals that the majority of these crucial innovations may be attributed to the first phase of the world system, and a major part of it, to Sumer. Not until the Information Age of contemporary experience has the world known a similar burst of creativity in this domain.

CLICK HERE FOR TABLE 3

At the start of the second major era, that of Eurasian cultural balance, "there existed four distinct regions of high culture in Eurasia", and "two thousand years later the physiognomy of Eurasia was recognizably the same" (McNeill 1963:249) , and we might add, persists to this day. Balance replaced dominance, establishing a condition not just of relative autonomy but also, more importantly, one in which each major world region contributed its share to world development, and shared in its evolution. What was the nature of that contribution?

Our model proposes that in this "classic" era, the major priority, and critical innovations, lay not in erecting great empires, but in "community-building". This was, indeed, the era of world religions. The Eastern Chou era of Chinese history brought forth Confucianism. The ideas of Confucius "catalyzed the institutional and intellectual definition of Chinese civilization" (McNeill 1963:232), and moulded the cadres of its scholar-officials. The teachings of Buddha came to be institutionalized in the Mauryan context in the Indian sub-contin ent, and then spread to influence West and Southeast Asia, and East Asia as well. Buddhism was organized around the practice of monastic communities. Christianity formed in the Mediterranean under Roman rule, and then shattered it. The Ummayad and Abbasid Caliphates became the framework for Islam, resolving the issue of "how the community of the faithful should be led and by what principles it should be governed" (ib.:429). Accounting for "much of the institutional pattern" that gave Islam its strength was "the strategic position of the mercantile class" (Hodgson 1993:107).

We observe that all four of these cases have in common the creation of a new basis for a potentially universal community; none succeeded to a full degree but each in its own way served to lay the foundations for a more inclusive world organization, but each in turn contributed their own important aspects to the building of community. We observe though a contrast with Karl Jaspers' concept of an "axial age" (-800 - -200), the age of he regards as that of Confucius, Buddha, and Socrates, an epoch at the center of world history during which all fundamental creations of current civilization had taken shape almost simultaneously across Eurasia. Our own "learning" conception is conceptually sequential.

If the classical era was, in its basic thrust, Eurasian, then the modern era might more appropriately be labeled "global", and we might wish to suspend judgment on the question whether this should be called the era of "Western dominance". If, as William McNeill (1983) has more recently urged, we see the modern world system as beginning to take-off as early as one thousand years ago, in Sung China,, then its complexion must a mixed one, with the Chinese Renaissance being followed by the Italian, and Western Europe only taking a leading position well into that process, after 1500. Maybe it is too early to give a final definition of that era whose likely reach might extend for some more centuries.

But we might be entitled to assert that, propelled by a powerful "organizational revolution", prominent forms of collective action, not old-fashioned empires, but nation-states, corporate business entities, armies and navies, universities, now dominate the social landscape that also includes a growing network of global institutions. That is how we would define the most striking social innovations of the modern age, and it is these innovations that have given substance to the term "world system". We can see the four phases of that process as preparatory and cultural (the Renaissance), that of the emergence of a nucleus of the world system in Western Europe, and currently the phase of world organization, yet to be followed by stabilization.

We have now traced world system processes through five millennia but we also observe that the substance of the world system did not become apparent until the most recent centuries. That is so because we are attempting to uncover a process by which the world system evolves, and that evolution always starts slowly at first and reaches a point of crystallization (via punctuation, as in punctuated equilibrium) only some distance along the way, usually in the third, the selection, stage of the process, that is at mid-point of the learning process. For the world system, that would be the stage of collective organization that has been under way for the past millennium, which is the time when the fact of world organization first started to become a reality.

Where all this might take us is a matter for informed speculation but the concept of "cosmopolitanism" is not incompatible with the "post-modern stabilization/adaptation" that is predicted by our model for the fourth phase of the world system process.

WORLD SYSTEM PROCESSES

What have we learnt so far about world system evolution? That a gross ordering scheme in evolutionary terms is at least conceivable and that a gross characterization of the epochs of world history in terms of (culturally-conceived) social priorities, and the major innovations responding to these priorities, is not inherently implausible. Such a model cannot be rejected as glaringly at variance with the conventional scheme of things, and is in fact better than could be expected from an exceedingly macro-model. Equally clear, we must also make this ordering more convincing by reducing the extended time-span between cause and effect, and by introducing additional mechanisms of less grandiose time-dimensions.

We have treated the conventional periodization as applying across the board to the world system process. But we noticed too that the basis of such periodizations is in the first place expressed along one dimension, the political or the geo-political one, because it invites us to view world system development through the lens of such concepts as Middle Eastern dominance, or Eurasian balance (that is, absence of dominance). Clearly, political evolution constitutes one aspects of the world system process, meaningfully related to other like processes. How might political world system evolution be explained, and how might such political process be related to, shall we say, the main currents of economic change in the world system?

We recall that we conceive the world system as composed (along the horizontal dimension) of a set of four self-similar, and nested, structures (enduring forms of networks of interactions): economic, political, social and cultural. We call these structures self-similar because each is subject to an evolutionary process of the same logical make-up, but the process proceeds at different time-scales. That is, the rate at which the economy changes is faster than developments in structural politics, etc. Because the scales of these processes differ, some might be thought of as nesting within others; that is e.g. economic changes may be thought of as occurring within a larger political framework. Nesting calls for synchronization, and that is why the time-scales of the several evolutionary processes must stand in a determinate relationship to each other. The whole forms a spectrum of processes of interlocking periodicities. We hypothesize the following relationships among these processes:

CLICK HERE TO SEE CHART

In other words, we propose that the constituent processes of the world system interlock in a determinate manner. While all these process undergo change at a constant rate, the periods of their processes differ in a determinate ratio. By that we mean that four periods of the world economy process are equal to two periods of the active zone process, and one period of center-hinterland process. The relationship, at the world level, is thus regulated by the relative scale of these various event sequences. That relationship, in turn, reflects what Talcott Parsons (1966:9,24,113) called the "cybernetic hierarchy" according to which "the longer the time perspective, and the broader the system involved, the greater is the relative importance of higher, rather than lower, factors, in the control hierarchy". In such terms, the overall process of world system evolution that we reviewed in the preceding section might be analyzed (or refracted) into four distinct processes that stand to each other in a relationship of 1:2:4:8, and each of which is composed of four phases, reflecting the operation of basic evolutionary mechanisms.

World system process We hypothesize that this is the process that gives overall shape to the world system, programs it, orders its priorities, and times the major phases we have just discussed. It takes its cue from the world information networks, and is at bottom a cultural process that gives a distinct texture to major epochs of world culture that we have already observed in Table 1.

Center-hinterland process The evolution of a human community and the growth of human solidarity is not a process of linear growth but one of persistent tension between the pressures to innovate that are the consequences of evolutionary developments and a necessary outcome of learning, and the demands for equality that is the operating requirement of every community. Innovations produce concentrations of metropolitan power, and peaks of prestige systems, often centered on opulent cities and powerful empires; forming in opposition to them are the hinterlands, or the margins of "civilized society" that from time to time organized themselves to effect a systemic leveling (or "dependency reversal"). It is hypothesized that major phases of center concentration, a millennium in length, alternate with equally significant intervals of hinterland assertiveness.

We borrow this pair of terms "center-hinterland" from A.G. Frank's recent (1990) studies. It parallels the conceptual pair of "core-periphery" but it needs to be distinguished from it because the latter is based upon a differential division of labor; the former is that of a social relationship that might be grounded also in differential distributions of political power, social prestige, and claims to innovation.

Active zone process An active zone is the spatial locus of innovation in the world system. Social and cultural evolution proceeds by means of innovation and its diffusion, and it flourishes in conditions that favor the generation of variety and evolutionary processes in general. The political seedbeds of such variety are not powerful empires that tend to attract the eye of historians but zones of autonomous entities, such as state systems, and intermediate political networks, and more broadly regimes and domains in which individuals and communities enjoy freedom and autonomy that favor creativity.

Thus conceived, active zones might be seen to serve as the capital zones of the world system, as long as they keep generating the innovations that respond to world problems. The active zone process is the political process that in each period of 2000 years focuses upon a broad geopolitical zone but that also in each of its phases (of about one half millennium) moves along spatially to a new region of the world system. Standard eras of world history might be seen also as periods of the active zone process.

Production/commerce A hypothesized world economy process defines changes in the major modes of the organization of production and exchange in respect of agriculture, mining and industry. Periods of productive development, and surges of new technologies (such as bronze, or iron) alternate with others that expand networks of interchange, pioneer new trade routes, and generally disperse such innovations. Such changes animate, and are in turn controlled by, the active zone process.

Model presented

Table 4 presents this model for visual inspection, to show how these processes coevolve. It spells out, in the third column the sequence of active zones that adds detail to our earlier discussion of geopolitical regions, and adduces other information that put some flesh on the bare bones of this structural argument.

The first column of Table 4, world system process, repeats the phases shown in Table 1, and we have already reviewed these, each also defining a major theme of cultural development. In turn, in column 2, we show each of the epochs of the world system comprising two phases of the center-hinterland process. We know that the core-building that produced the flowering of Mesopotamia, of Egypt, and of the Indus Valley, was ru dely interrupted by a wave of "high barbarism". "Beginning about 1700 BC, a wave of barbarian invasions initiated far reaching changes in the political and cultural map of the Middle East" (McNeill 1963:110). Several groups of invaders, having mastered the techniques of chariot warfare, collaborated in overrunning the rising centers of ancient civilization in the Middle East and the upshot was the formation, in that region, of what McNeill calls a "great society", as well as the projection of strong influences on the formation of civilization in other parts of Eurasia. In other words, a pattern of core building was followed by a period of leveling.

The dispersion affected by the barbarian invasions then served to consolidate the core of four civilizations, East Asian, Indian, Mideastern, and European, that came to constitute McNeill's "balance of Eurasia". It is within that balance that each of these contributed to the major process of community-building that was discussed in the preceding section. But after the year 200 the structures thus erected once again came under the pressure of a "barbarian breakthrough" (McNeill 1963:385 ff). The movements of Germanic tribes that broke up the Roman empire were part of the same great migration as the barbarian occupation of North China, and the Ephalite invasions of India. The eruption of the tribes of Arabia upon the Mediterranean world after 632 completed what appeared to be another sustained process of systemic leveling.

In the early modern era it appeared for a moment as though under Mongol rule, China, might become the center of the world system. But the attempts at world empire collapsed, and the active zone moved to the Meditarranean. We are familiar with the thought that after 1500 the center came to reside in West Europe, in a manner such that various parts of the world system became increasingly dependent upon it, in colonial and semi-colonial situations.

CLICK HERE FOR TABLE 4

Our analysis would predict that, once again, this extensive period of systemic concentration might be due for a reversal: the world system might have entered, after 1850, onto a movement of systematic leveling, though hopefully at a higher level of organization. This leveling might be taking the form of democratization, in which an initially small core of democratic societies (about 10 per cent of the world population at the end of the 19th century) might be gradually bringing into the fold of a future democratic community a larger and larger portion of the world's peoples (approaching 50 per cent of a much larger population at the turn of the 21st century).

How might this be so? On this analysis, the center-hinterland process is now in its second period (of 4000 years each). The first, labeled here "Rough World", was in a sense unsurprising, for in the course of it the splendor of civilization was regularly, albeit at long intervals, balanced by the excesses of those who attacked it in order to share in it, and sometimes to destroy it. While this was indeed a rough world, maybe there was also in it an element of rough justice.

Can the rough edges be take off the world system? Robert Axelrod (1984) has argued that even in a "nasty world", "nice strategies" can arise as mutations of established operating procedures, and in certain conditions, namely those of clustering, might not just survive but also prosper. Let us therefore entertain the proposition that the second period of the center-hinterland process might be one experiencing a move toward a "nicer world".

At first, we would, once again, expect a stage of reconcentration, powered by prodigious innovation in forms of global organization, giving rise to much dependency. But the same process would also be responsible for setting off mutant forms, in Sung China, or in Italy, launching experiments, reformist, republican, and liberal that build up potential for social and political development. It is from those mutant forms that cooperative arrangements could arise and lift the raw conflict among center and hinterland to a higher level of performance. The diffusion of democracy since the 19th century across the world, to i.a. Japan, India, Eastern Europe, and parts of South America, is beginning to create conditions in which demands for greater equality might find expression in forms that are "nicer".

The sequence of active zones (in column 3 of Table 4) has been neither arbitrary nor unsystematic. The progression described by that sequence has been along zones of spatial contiguity, and has successively lent priority to cultural, social, political, and economic factors. Thus in Confucianism, for instance emphasis is placed on scholarship and learning; in Buddhism, on the development of the monastic community; in Christianity, on church organizational factors, and in Islam, on the evolution of long-range communications based on pilgrimages and trade-routs facilitated by that community.

The active zone process can be documented with the help of data on world urban populations, cities in active zones being the seedbeds of major innovations. Recent research (Bosworth 1995:198ff) shows that the process appears to capture "those regions whose population growth outpaced those of the rest of the world, with each active zone building upon the foundations of its forerunner". For each of the zones identified in Column 3 after -1000, that is for all those for which usable data are available, the population of the top-25 cities in that active zone exceeded that of every other region in the relevant time period.

As expected, the active zone is shown to have been, in most cases, an arena occupied by autonomous political systems, from the city states of Mesopotamia, to the interstate systems of the Middle East, the Eastern Chou, and India. Rome splintered not long after its emperor embraced Christianity; and the Islamic Caliphates were noted for the flexibility of their political organization. The city-states of Ancient Greece might appear as a notable omission but it was in their shaping of the Hellenized society of the Mediterranean created by Rome and inherited by Christianity that Greek culture found its enduring place.

At about 1000, it appeared as though Sung China, then the most conspicuous member of the East Asian region might take the lead in the world system, such that this could be regarded as "The Era of Chinese Predominance" (McNeill 1982:24 ff). But the Sung first lost the North, and then fell, in the South, before the onslaught of the Mongols. It is the Mongols' design for world empire at the center of Eurasian land mass and the dominance of their huge cavalry armies that defined this age as one of " Eurasian transition", from East Asia to Europe. The Mongol's project extended from China over most of Eurasia, but it never completely materialized, nor did that of Timur, and imposing though both were, they soon collapsed under their own weight just as the last European attempts at medieval empire (those of Charles of Anjou) crumbled even before getting properly underway. The republican regimes of Genoa, and then Venice, were the initial beneficiaries of that transition, took up the challenge and became the springboards from which West European power was projected world wide after 1500.

The fourth column of Table 4 suggests the outlines of the evolution of the world economy (see also Modelski and Thompson 1995:Ch.8). The world economy process begins with Bronze as

a basic new technology, with implications for weapons production and tool-making in particular. That technology favored urbanization, helped to raise levels of production, and created conditions favoring increased trade. Then the Bronze age is rounded off with the emergence, in the Fertile Crescent, after about -1500, of a "civilized core area" (McNeill 1963:113) serving i.a. as the framework of economic organization.

Between -1200 and -1000 in the Middle East and in Europe (though in China not until -600), iron working begins to assume general importance, replacing bronze as the primary metal for tools and weapons. The "closure of the Eurasian ecumene" in turn provides the opportunity for a notable expansion of long-term trade, chiefly by land but also by sea, with the Silk Roads assuming a key role in that process in the fourth period in particular.

The modern age is clearly notable for the establishment of more flexible and productive "market economies", especially in the sense of an increasing differentiation between economy and polity, the consolidation of the economy as a potentially self-organizing system, and the increased role of autonomous, and increasingly corporate, business organizations. The groundwork for that development was laid over the past millennium, and more recently, say after 1850, conditions began to ripen for the creation of a world market, as the framework of exchange in a now strikingly productive world economy.

GLOBALIZATION

So far so good. World system evolution has now assumed a fuller-bodied complexion and presents a more coherent picture. The "resolution" of its analysis - represented by its smallest phase period - is now reduced from two thousand to about 250 years, but it does remain quite a "wholesale" view of human history, and especially so for the modern period.

What is it precisely that we are trying to explain? Once again, our point of departure is a set of political data, namely the observed sequence of world powers exercising leadership in the world system in the past millennium. That sequence has been fully described, and commented upon i.a. by Paul Kennedy (1988), and while the particulars of that description vary among observers, in general outline, and in particular in the role of Britain and the United States, it is now hardly in doubt (Thompson 1988). An account of that sequence does not appear in our earlier analysis (e.g. in Table 4 and the active zone process). What we need is a causal account of that sequence on a more detailed scale, and an explanation of how it might relate to crucial economic, social, and cultural processes at that same level. In effect we are trying to explain globalization in its several aspects.

Global processes

Let us first make the analysis more fine-grained for the modern era. Standard treatments set the start of "modernity", or of the modern world system , at about 1500, give or take a few decades, and it is of course quite obvious that a "birth" of sorts did indeed occur at that time. But students of evolutionary processes may wish to go beyond birth, to the sources of such events and ask: when and in what situations did "inception" occur. That is why our world system model suggests that the "inception" (or "conception?) of the modern world must be sought earlier, as early as maybe 930, or thereabouts, and accordingly we shall assign the onset of globalization to that date.

Second, our model needs to take account of the increased organizational complexity of modernity: the rise of nation-states, multinational enterprises, even international institutions. In that respect we know already that this modern era is one of "collective organization". We also know that the pre-modern world, organizationally speaking, was basically a two-tier arrangement, one that combined a glittering world of the "great tradition" based on cities, courts, and temples, with the multitude of the "little traditions" of the village peasantry (Modelski 1987:24-6). We hypothesize that the modern era produced (along the vertical dimension) a division of this two-tier set-up into a potentially four-fold structure comprised of local, national, regional, and global layers of organization, and that the inception of that process of vertical differentiation coincides with the beginning of that era.

In other words, at about 1000 we expect the world system to be generating the beginnings of an analytically distinct process that, in essence, gives form, in greater detail, to the world system at the global level. Or else, we might say, that global mechanisms (such as world powers competing for global leadership, or leading sectors driving the global economy) motivate changes in the world at large. The global system process, (that is, globalization) might in turn be refracted (or decomposed) into (nested) cultural, social, political, and economic elements (each subject to self-similarity) and giving rise to a new set structures at the global level. We label these processes as follows:

CLICK HERE FOR CHART 2

Globalization, in those terms, might be defined as the formation of global institutions, and might best be viewed as a spectrum of these four processes. We observe that the period of each of these structure-building processes at the global level equals one phase (that is, one quarter) of the world system periods discussed in the preceding section.

"Global system process" might be supposed to program the global system, much in the same way that we have observed the world system process to function. Its working depends on the more detailed specification of the world system priority of "collective organization", and its phases represent the steps by which such organization might be thought of as emerging at the global level: Preconditions; Global nucleus; Global organization; Consolidation. Global community process" ; traces the evolution of community at the global level of organization. Two periods of that process might be distinguished: those of "experiments", and of "democracy". The terms are inspired by Robert Axelrod's (1984) previously mentioned analysis of the evolution of cooperation. In it he proposes that, in a "nasty" world, cooperative behavior might arise in a "mutant" form, constituting an experimental exploration of the potential for community. We propose that reform movements in Sung China ca. 1100, and republican experiments in the cities of Northern Italy ca. 1300 constituted two sets of suc h trials, but that it was religious turmoil of the European Reformation, centering in particular upon the Dutch Republic that laid the foundation of cumulative growth of a nucleus of a global system, embodied in particular in the "liberal alliance" with England. In that way we can say that some of these experiments succeeded, in conditions of clustering, and we propose that conditions particularly favorable to such clustering have arisen since about 1850, laying the groundwork for what might become a future a global democratic community, in a process first anticipated by Alexis de Tocqueville, writing in 1835, who postulated the ultimate success of the process of democratization on the basis of his American experience. Why not call the successive periods of global community formation "D-waves" (for democracy)?

Global polity process" has a period of 500 years that corresponds to one phase of the active zone process. Each such period therefore tends to center upon one region of the world system, and we name these periods provisionally after the phases of the active zone process as we may suppose that the locus of the global system is the active zone of the world system. That is we name the first period "Eurasian transition", followed by "West European" and Post-West-European" periods. The phases of that process consist of successive instances of the rise and decline of world powers, the mechanism whereby certain nation-states h ave been selected for the role of leadership at the global level.

Some key elements of this process are now well understood, and documented, in particular in its link to shifts in sea power concentration (Modelski & Thompson 1988), and its grounding in global economics (Modelski and Thompson 1995); the recognition of the special role of the United States, Britain, and also the Netherlands, is now shared by the several variants of structural-historical approaches to world politics (Thompson 1988). The present study extends the reach of that process back to about 1000 (as shown below).

Global economy process" describes structural changes in world-wide commercial and industrial arrangements with a period of some 225-250 years, within each of which four K-waves are nested. These changes reflect movements in the world economic process previously discussed, from "Market Economy" to "World Market", and spell out the finer structure of that transformation at the global level, through periods of "Sung Breakthrough", "Commercial-Nautical Revolution", "Oceanic Trade", and "Industrial Take-off". In other words, we see the Industrial Revolution of the 18th century as one, albeit dramatic, point along a long path of growth for the global economy, that is now being followed by the "Information Economy".

Some data

Table 5 presents a model of global system processes derived from these considerations, and adduces some data, since 930, that help lend face validity to it. We note that the resolution of the evolutionary process is now down to 55 years (the length of one K-wave, in column four). Let us add a brief commentary on each of those processes, some of which are coming to be quite well understood.

Eurasian transition

There is no reason to expect that the breakthrough to a global system could have occurred at only one place. Table 4 presents a concept of an "Eurasian inception" of the global system, namely that such a breakthrough occurred, in Eurasia, at about 1000, both in China, and soon afterwards, in Mediterranean Europe. The developments in China looked, for a while, more substantial and promising and it was there that the technologies of printing, gunpowder, and compass navigation, so crucial to that breakthrough, first arose. There was a surge of sea power, and a notable expansion in water borne trade. "Between 1000 and 1450, China's social structure teetered on the verge of a fundamental change analogous to the rise of the bourgeoisie in medieval and early modern Europe" (McNeill 1963: 525).

But Sung China faltered, and failed fully to carry through to the global level. The Sung saw themselves as the bearers of China's classical tradition (recently reinforced though the printing of Confucian classics), but they had to contend with aggressive Sinicized dynasties of Inner Asian origin that ruled much of North China. In 1004 they reached a stand-off with the Khitans (whose regime is known by the Chinese dynasty name of Liao). But the Liao dynasty was destroyed, with Sung help, in 1125, by the Jurchens who took the dynastic name of Chin. By 1224 Chin rule in turn succumbed to the Mongols under Genghiz Khan who then took on the Southern Sung and, under Kublai Khan, completed the conquest of China in 1279 (and assumed the dynastic name of Yuan). It seems that the task of mastering the nomadic threat from the North never allowed full energy to be devoted to activities of global scope.

CLICK HERE FOR TABLE 5

Structural politics in China 930-1420 could be presented as a sequence of four dynastic cycles, each of about 100-120 years in length, and each composed of the four phases of the political learning process: agenda-setting, coalition-building, macrodecision, and execution. It will be seen that China's structural evolution over this period was timed by four macrodecisions: the war with the Liao; the war with Chin, that forced a shift of the capital from Kaifeng to Hangchow and inaugurated the Southern Sung; China's conquest by the Mongols, who established themselves in Peking; and the Ming rebellion that expelled the Mongols, and that coincided with the general collapse of Mongol power, in large part under the attack of Timur (+1405). Ming rule was first founded at Nanking, with a potentially maritime orientation, but despite the famed expeditions to the Indian ocean that followed, China soon turned inward, and the move to Peking in 1421 put a seal on that development.

We have already made note of the fact that the rule of the Mongols extended not only to China, but throughout a major portion of Eurasia, in an imposing structure that embodied a bid for world empire. But that bid soon crashed, in just the way that similar imperial bids, though on a more modest scale, also collapsed in the Far West at the same time. The same model that was just used to outline the evolution of East Asia could also be employed, with an identical time grid, to depict the salient developments in Mediterranean Europe. The first three cycles had the same imperial bent as those of the Chinese regional system: an attempt at Byzantine recovery that collapsed after the disaster at Manzikert; the Holy Roman Empire and the Hohenstauffen bid to rule the Mediterranean; and the French (Anjou-) and Papal bid for universal monarchy, launched at the peak of Mongol power, and whose defeat was signaled by the Sicilian Vespers. All three were carried through to a macrodecision, but failed to make good on execution.

Running parallel, though, to these imperial gestures was a series of bids for commercial supremacy by prominent Italian city states (Braudel 1984:106-111), beginning with Amalfi, a dependency of Byzantium, followed by Pisa, in league with the Holy Roman Emperors, and then Genoa, working with the Popes and the French, and indirectly coordinate, via Black Sea trade and alliances, with the Mongol world empire. Each city was in turn routed by its successor, at the time of, and synchronous with, the macrodecision of the imperial bids: Pisa sacked Amalfi; Genoa crushed Pisa, and Venice defeated Genoa after much bitter fighting, some of it at the entrance to the lagoon, and for a time profited from the victories of Timur. But it was only Venice that stood on its own, dominated its golden "quattrocento", and served as the regional prototype of a global power and a bridge to the next phase of the global system process.

The global polity process and the long cycle

It remains for us to spell out in greater detail what Table 5 has already shown, how the sequence comprised of the rise and decline of world powers (the long cycle of global politics) is the driver of the global polity process. Likewise, the sequence of global leading sectors that represents successive K-waves propels the evolution of the global economy.

In the global polity process (shown in Table 6) the Chinese antecedents, and Italian prototypes, were inchoate, proto-global, political sequences, laying at the regional level the foundations of future global enterprises. With Portugal we move beyond laying the foundations, to building, first, the nucleus of the global system, and then adding to it with each successive cycle. We note that, too, the four-phase evolutionary structure remains the same but that, in contrast to its fumbling beginnings, the process is now more steady and, from the Dutch case onward, noticeably cumulative. In the "post-West-European" period, we see the beginnings of global organization.

This makes it clear that the long cycle, the sequence of world powers that we sought to explain, is in fact a mechanism of a global evolutionary process, wherein powerful nation-states, pursuing their own goals, forwarded the task of global political construction. We note, too, that the resolution of the analysis has now been reduced to 25-30 years, that is to what is usually considered to be the time span of a generation (the time it takes for a generation to replace itself).


CLICK HERE FOR TABLE 6

The global economy process and K-waves

Our global economy process comes close to what Fernand Braudel (1984:76-88) identified as the "secular trends" in the European economy, each linked to four Kondratieffs (K-waves). It places less emphasis than Braudel does on the ups and downs of the economy and on its price trends than on ongoing transformations in economic structures at the global level. The two systematizations may be compared as follows:

CLICK HERE FOR CHART 3

As might be seen, Braudel's "up trends" start one or two generations later than the global economy process (that accounts for origins), yet the broad thrust his argument is not dissimilar, as might be expected, given the fact that Western Europe w as most of that time at the center of the global economy. It should be prefaced, though, with the surge of economic growth in Sung China (930-1190) that led into these developments.

The present analysis spells out these trends in greater detail (see in particular Modelski and Thompson 1995, and Thompson 1988) and shows that each of these major periods, in turn, is driven by four K-waves (Table 5). In that way we spotlight those global leading economic sectors that were experiencing the most significant growth spurts, acting as the moving forces of an emerging global economy. This work lays the groundwork of a full documentation of the systematic interdependence of K-waves and long cycles of the global polity.

WORLD SYSTEM AND CIVILIZATION

We have now analyzed the world system into a number of processes of lesser range and magnitude. But we also know that the world system is not a free-standing or autonomously propagating process. It is likely to be, in a nesting fashion, part of some larger-scale arrangement. That larger arrangement, too, is likely to be subject to evolutionary tendencies. What might be that arrangement?

These are "sweeping" but important questions: is there a large process of which world system evolution (with a period of 8000 years) is a part? how might world system evolution place in the larger scheme of the evolution of the human species (homo sapiens sapiens)? how do we explain the origins, or the inception, of the world system, and what is the larger framework in which that system must be situated?

These are "good" questions. Could it be that at first, human (homo sapiens sapiens) evolution wrought the differentiation of humanity from nature. Could that pre-historical period, extending for over 30,000 years, be thought of as having comprised four phases? It might have begun with the adoption of a fully efficient human language, including the use of syntax. Such a cultural breakthrough, we might suppose, would in turn promote kinship linkages and family groups in a next phase of that evolution. Then, at the peak of the last ice age, humans would have been driven into caves and other permanent settlements. Finally, some 10,000 years ago, we might have reached the start of agriculture in to-day's Middle East, and soon elsewhere. This celebrated Agricultural Revolution laid down the necessary preconditions for the next step in human evolution: the rise of civilization.

What is not in doubt is that the centuries before -3000 mark a strategic turning point, toward sociiality. They might be seen as the start of world system evolution, and of all the arrangements that over time have come to make up our major social institutions. But they also signaled the onset of civilization, a deeper change that extended not only to society but also to culture, human nature, and to human relations to the environment. We might define (singular) civilization (a word whose root is the same as that for city) as a condition of humanity characterized by urbanity, or a culture of urban living, one that might be contrasted with barbarism in a condition of nature. City life is made possible by agricultural surpluses, so that the city becomes the first large-scale human cultural artifact and urban life marks the differentiation of culture from society in human evolution. It is a characteristic of human evolution to have entered upon civilization (and history proper) with the onset of urbanization, over 5000 years ago, and it is a stage that we are still living through, and are likely to continue in well into the future.

Malays (ethnic group)




Introduction

Malays (Malay: Melayu) are an ethnic group of Austronesian peoples predominantly inhabiting the Malay Peninsula, the east coast of Sumatra, the coast of Borneo, and the smaller islands between these locations. The Malay ethnic group is distinct from the concept of a Malay race, which encompasses a wider group of people, including most of Indonesia and the Philippines. The Malay language is a member of the Austronesian family of languages.

Austronesian People

[Austronesian people are a population in Oceania and Southeast Asia that speak languages of the Austronesian languages family. Austronesian peoples include: Taiwanese aborigines; the majority ethnic groups of East Timor, Indonesia, Malaysia, the Philippines, Brunei, Madagascar, Micronesia, and Polynesia, as well as the Polynesian peoples of New Zealand and Hawaii, and the Austronesian peoples of Melanesia. They are also found in the Pattani region of Thailand, and the Cham areas of Vietnam, Cambodia, and Hainan, China (remnants of the Champa kingdom which covered central and southern Vietnam). The territories settled by Austronesian peoples are known collectively as Austronesia.]

Malay Race

[The concept of a Malay race (Malay: Bangsa Melayu) was proposed by the German scientist Johann Friedrich Blumenbach (1752-1840).[1] Since Blumenbach, many anthropologists have rejected his theory of five races, citing the enormous complexity of classifying races. However, the term Malay is still often used in this context, and it is the basis for Malay identity within the country of Malaysia. However, the term Malay Race is rarely used in Indonesia. The concept of a "Malay race" differs with that of the Malay ethnic group centred around Malaysia and parts of the Indonesian island of Sumatra.

Origins of Malay Race Term

In his 1775 doctoral dissertation titled De generis humani varietate nativa (On the Natural Varieties of Mankind), Blumenbach outlined four main human races by skin color, namely Caucasian (white), Ethiopian (black), Native American (red), and Mongolian (yellow).

By 1795, Blumenbach added another race called 'Malay' which he considered to be a subcategory of both the Ethiopian and Mongoloid races. The Malay race were those of a "brown color, from olive and a clear mahogany to the darkest clove or chestnut brown." Blumenbach expanded the term "Malay" to include the inhabitants of the Marianas, the Philippines, the Malukus, Sundas, as well as Pacific Islands such as Tahitians. He considered a Tahitian skull he had received to be the missing link; showing the transition between the "primary" race, the Caucasians, and the "degenerate" race, the Negroids.

Blumenbach writes:

Malay variety. Tawny-coloured; hair black, soft, curly, thick and plentiful; head moderately narrowed; forehead slightly swelling; nose full, rather wide, as it were diffuse, end thick; mouth large. upper jaw somewhat prominent with the parts of the face when seen in profile, sufficiently prominent and distinct from each other. This last variety includes the islanders of the Pacific Ocean, together with the inhabitants of the Marianne, the Philippine, the Molucca and the Sunda Islands, and of the Malayan peninsula. I wish to call it the Malay, because the majority of the men of this variety, especially those who inhabit the Indian islands close to the Malacca peninsula, as well as the Sandwich, the Society, and the Friendly Islanders, and also the Malambi of Madagascar down to the inhabitants of Easter Island, use the Malay idiom.]

History

The Encyclopedia of Malaysia: Early History, has pointed out a total of three theories of the origin of Malay:

· The Yunnan theory, Mekong river migration (published 1889)

· The New Guinea theory (published 1965)

· The Taiwan theory (published 1997)

The ancestors of Malays are believed to be seafarers knowledgeable in oceanography. They moved around from island to island in great distances between New Zealand and Madagascar, and they served as navigation guide, crew and labour to Indian, Persian and Chinese traders for nearly 2000 years. Over the years they settled at various places and adopted various cultures and religions. Notable Malay seafarers of today are Moken and Orang laut.

Some historians suggested they were descendants of Austronesian-speakers who migrated from the Philippines and originally came from Taiwan. Malay culture reached its golden age during Srivijayan times and they practiced Buddhism, Hinduism, and their native Animism before converting to Islam in the 15th century.

Etymology

In the History of Jambi, the word Melayu originated from a river with name Melayu River near to Batang Hari River of today's Muara Jambi, Jambi province of Sumatra, Indonesia and even a Melayu Kingdom existed from the record of Yi Jing (a Tang Dynasty Buddhist monk) and archaeological research of Jambi, large numbers of ancient artifacts and ancient architectures of the Melayu Kingdom have been found with photo evidence. However further tracing the root of the word, a small town in Tamil district appeared called Malai Yur which means "Land of Mountains" (malai means mountain and yur means land), a reference to the hilly nature of the Malay Archipelago. Other ancient Indian sources , the Purana text, claimed "Malayadvipa" on Sumatra with the meaning 'dvipa' land surrounded by water, while the ancient Sanskrit word Himalaya means 'snow mountain'. "Maleu-kolon" was used by Ptolemy which was also derived from Sanskrit 'malayakom' or 'malaikurram', according to G. E. Gerini that was to refer to Tanjung Kuantan while Roland Bradell claimed it on Tanjung Penyabung, both in the peninsula. (see Tamil place names in Malaysia)

The word Melayu began in use during the time of Sultanate of Melaka, founded by the fleeing prince Parameswara, from the declining Melayu Kingdom of Srivijaya in Palembang. And the word was in popular use in 17th century onwards.

During the European colonization, the word "Malay" was adopted into English via the Dutch word "Malayo", itself from Portuguese "Malaio", which originates from the Malay word "Melayu". According to one popular theory, the word Melayu means "migrating" or "fleeing", which might refer to the high mobility of these people across the region (cf. Javanese verb 'mlayu' means "to run", cognate with Malay verb 'melaju', means "to accelerate") or perhaps the original meaning is "distant, far away" (cf. Tagalog 'malayo') with the root word 'layo', which means 'distance' or 'far' in Tagalog and some Malayo-Polynesian languages.

Chinese sources

Early Chinese text "Ma-la-yu" (Chinese: 末羅瑜) written by monk Yi Jing was an independent kingdom. In later dynasties, such as the Mongol Yuan Dynasty and the Ming Dynasty, the word Ma-La-Yu was mentioned often (in the history of China) to refer to a nation from southern sea with different spelling due to the change of dynasty.

(Chinese: 木剌由) - Bok-la-yu, Mok-la-yu

(Chinese: 麻里予兒) - Ma-li-yu-er

(Chinese: 巫来由) - Oo-lai-yu (traced from the written source of monk Xuan Zang)

(Chinese: 無来由) - Wu-lai-yu

Kedah and Melaka literature

According to Kedah Annals, Kadaram (Kedah Kingdom 630-1136) was founded by Maharaja Derbar Raja of Gemeron, Persia around 630 CE, and also alleged that the bloodline of Kedah royalties coming from Alexander The Great. The other Malay literature, Sejarah Melayu too alleged that they were the descendants of Alexander The Great.

Deutero Malays

Combination of the colonial Kambujas of Hindu-Buddhism faith, the Indo-Persian royalties and traders as well as traders from southern China and elsewhere along the ancient trade routes, these peoples together with the aborigine Negrito Orang Asli and native seafarers and Proto Malays intermarried each others and thus a new group of peoples was formed and became to be known as the Deutero Malays, today they are commonly known as the Malays.

Alternate uses of the term

The name Malay is sometimes used to describe the concept of a Malay race, which includes all the ethnic groups inhabiting the Malay Archipelago and which are not of older aboriginal stock.

The term Melayu (Malay person in the Malay Language), in the Federal Constitution of Malaysia, refers to a person who professes Islam, habitually speaks the Malay language, conforms to Malay custom and who has at least one ancestor from the Malay Peninsula or Singapore.

Ethnic group vs. cultural sphere

The term "Malay" can refer to the ethnic group who live in the Malay peninsula (which include the southernmost part of Thailand called Patani and Satun) and east Sumatra as well as the cultural sphere that encompass a large part of the archipelago.

The Malay ethnic group is the majority in Malaysia and Brunei and a sizable minority in Singapore and Indonesia, and they form the majority in the five southernmost provinces of Thailand which historically made up the old Malay kingdom of Patani. These people speak various dialects of Malay language. The peninsular dialect as spoken in the Malaysian states of Pahang, Selangor and Johor is the standard speech among Malays in Malaysia and Singapore. In the Malay peninsula, the Kelantanese dialect in its purest form is the most difficult to understand. Other peninsula dialects include the Kedah-Perlis dialect, the Melakan dialect, the Minangkabau dialect of Negeri Sembilan, the Perak dialect and the Terengganu dialect. In Thailand, Malays of Satun speak the Kedah-Perlis dialect while those in the Patani provinces speak the Kelantanese lingo. Meanwhile, the Riau dialect of eastern Sumatra has been adopted as a national tongue, Indonesian, for the whole Indonesian population.The ethnic Malay have had a Muslim culture since the 15th century.

In Malaysia, the majority of the population is made up of ethnic Malays while the minorities consist of southern Chinese (e.g. Hokkien and Cantonese), southern Indians (mainly Tamils), non-ethnic Malay indigenous peoples (e.g. Iban and Kadazan), as well as Eurasians.

Malay cultural influences filtered out throughout the archipelago, such as the monarchical state, religion (Hinduism/Buddhism in the first millennium AD, Islam in the second millennium), and the Malay language. The influential Srivijaya kingdom had unified the various ethnic groups in southeast Asia into a convergent cultural sphere for almost a millennium. It was during that time that vast borrowing of Sanskrit words and concepts facilitated the advanced linguistic development of Malay as a language. Malay was the regional lingua franca, and Malay-based creole languages existed in most trading ports in Indonesia.

Malay
Melayu

Total population

c. 22 million

Regions with significant populations

Majority populations

Malaysia

12.3 million (2006 estimate)

Brunei

0.25 million (2006 estimate)

Minority populations

Indonesia

6.9 million (2000 census)

Thailand

1.9 million (2006 estimate)

Singapore

0.45 million (2000 census)

Languages

Malay, Indonesian, Yawi, Thai

Religion

Sunni Islam (approx. 99.9%)

Related ethnic groups

Malaysian Malays, Malay Singaporean,Overseas Malays.

Sumber: Wikipedia, Melayuonline,sejarahkedah,ATMA dll

Rakan-rakan Pembaca Budiman